個人資料
正文

經濟衰退是不可避免的 他們錯的原因

(2024-05-05 15:04:24) 下一個

觀點:經濟學家表示,經濟衰退是不可避免的。這就是他們錯的原因。

作者:加裏·N·史密斯 2024 年 1 月 22 日
https://www.marketwatch.com/story/recession-was-inevitable-economists-said-heres-why-they-were-wrong-2edac573

對基於貨幣政策的預測持懷疑態度

約翰·霍普金斯大學經濟學教授史蒂夫·H·漢克 (Steve H. Hanke) 在 2022 年 8 月接受 CNBC 采訪時預測:“2023 年我們將經曆一場嚴重的經濟衰退。” 2023 年 4 月,他再次發出警告:“我們知道經濟衰退已經是板上釘釘的事情了,”他說。許多其他經濟學家也預測 2023 年將出現經濟衰退。他們錯了。

大多數衰退預測都是基於合理的假設,即美聯儲將采取一切必要措施將通脹降至央行 2% 的目標水平。在美聯儲1979年開始的通貨膨脹大戰期間,美聯儲主席保羅·沃爾克被問及緊縮貨幣政策是否會導致經濟衰退。他立即回答:“是的,而且越快越好。”

在 1980 年的另一次談話中,沃爾克表示,“直到最後一聲鋸齒聲平息”他才會滿意——指的是高利率對住宅、工廠和辦公樓建設造成的破壞性影響。

到 2022 年,隨著通貨膨脹率有可能達到兩位數水平,就像 1979 年的情況一樣,美聯儲觀察人士自然認為美聯儲將再次將利率提高到足夠高的水平,從而引發足以壓垮通貨膨脹的衰退。令他們驚訝的是,美聯儲實現了軟著陸,降低了通脹率,但沒有引發經濟衰退。

閱讀:通脹“遠未消亡”:為何一位大型資產管理公司懷疑美國能否達到 2%

漢克的推理更加教條,關注的是美國的貨幣供應量而不是利率。他長期以來一直認為貨幣數量論在貨幣與通貨膨脹之間提供了緊密的聯係。因此,舉例來說,如果直升機在全國各地飛行,從天而降的錢,從而使貨幣供應量增加一倍,價格也會增加一倍,而生活將繼續不受幹擾。

這個簡單化的模型存在幾個問題。一是它假設速度——國內生產總值與貨幣供應量的比率——是恒定的。例如,如果這個比率為 5,那麽平均每一美元每年將被用於購買國內生產的商品和服務五次。這個比率沒有理由應該是5或任何其他特定數字,特別是因為貨幣被用來購買許多不包含在GDP中的東西,包括中間產品、進口產品、股票和其他金融資產,以及房地產和其他現有的實物資產。

第二個問題是,沒有明確的最佳衡量貨幣的方法。與許多其他貨幣主義者一樣,漢克青睞 M2,這一衡量標準包括現金、各種銀行存款和零售貨幣市場基金。 M2 的想法是衡量人們可以根據需要支出的現成資金。房間裏的大象是,許多購買是通過信用卡、消費者和商業貸款進行的。沒有好的方法來衡量這些限製支出的程度。

盡管如此,漢克經常依靠貨幣數量論來論證 M2 與通貨膨脹之間存在緊密的一一對應的聯係。例如,他在 2023 年寫道,“速度和實際產出增長非常接近恒定,而且……貨幣供應增長率和通脹幾乎是一對一的關係。”

這個結論顯然是錯誤的,但我在這裏擔心的是漢克在 2022 年 8 月基於 M2 增長放緩對 2023 年“嚴重衰退”的預測。

我們讓市場變得有意義

通過 MarketWatch 的實時新聞和分析,了解當今的全球商業實踐、市場動態、經濟政策等如何影響您。

貨幣主義者喜歡指責美聯儲。

漢克並不是最後一個堅持的貨幣主義者。 Motley Fool 1 月 7 日的一篇文章指出,M2 在過去一年中下降了 2%,並警告說,“M2 的下降曆來是經濟衰退的先兆”。盡管文章確實指出曆史事件有點過時了(1878年、1893年、1921年和1931-1933年),但它仍然發出了不祥的警告:“前四次事件都導致了美國經濟的通貨緊縮蕭條,失業率大幅上升。”
貨幣主義者喜歡指責美聯儲,但美聯儲並不直接控製M2等貨幣總量。美聯儲利用公開市場操作來控製基礎貨幣——銀行外貨幣加上銀行準備金。 M2 和其他貨幣總量是由公共決定內生決定的,即如何在 M2 中包含或不包含的事物之間分配其財富。

另一個複雜的因素是美元是一些國家的官方貨幣

在許多其他國家,它是一種非官方的交換媒介,並被中央銀行廣泛持有作為外匯儲備。現在幾乎一半的美元都存放在美國境外。

底線是,沒有任何有說服力的理由說明M2應該與基礎貨幣緊密掛鉤。但實際上並非如此。從M2與基礎貨幣的比率這個數字可以看出,這種聯係是多麽的鬆散。 2008年M2與基礎貨幣的比率急劇下降,是因為美聯儲為防止大衰退演變成第二次大蕭條而增加基礎貨幣,而M2卻幾乎沒有變化。將 M2 稱為貨幣供應量是一種嚴重的誤導,就好像它是由美聯儲控製的一樣。

這些不同的考慮並不意味著美聯儲無能為力。隻要央行官員認為失業符合我們的最佳利益,他們當然可以縮減流動性並提高利率,從而引發經濟衰退。這些考慮的真正含義是,認為 M2 與通脹或產出之間存在緊密聯係的想法是愚蠢的,並且根據 M2 的波動做出預測是危險的。

加裏·N·史密斯 (Gary N. Smith) 是波莫納學院 (Pomona College) 弗萊徹·瓊斯 (Fletcher Jones) 經濟學教授,發表了數十篇研究文章和 17 本書,其中包括最近與他人合著的《現代價值投資的力量:超越指數、算法和阿爾法》與瑪格麗特·史密斯(帕爾格雷夫·麥克米倫,2023)。

Opinion: Recession was inevitable, economists said. Here's why they were wrong.

By Gary N. Smith Jan. 22, 2024 
 
Be skeptical of predictions based on monetary policy
 
In an August 2022 CNBC interview, Steve H. Hanke, a Johns Hopkins University economics professor, predicted: “We’re going to have one whopper of a recession in 2023.” In April 2023, he repeated the warning: “We know the recession is baked in the cake,” he said. Many other economists also anticipated a recession in 2023. They were wrong.

Most recession predictions were based on the reasonable assumption that the U.S. Federal Reserve would do whatever was necessary to bring inflation down to the central bank’s 2% target level. During the Fed’s great war on inflation that began in 1979, Fed Chair Paul Volcker was asked if the tight money policies would cause a recession. He answered immediately, “Yes, and the sooner the better.”

In another conversation in 1980, Volcker said that he wouldn’t be satisfied “until the last buzz saw is silenced” — a reference to the devastating effects of higher interest rates on the construction of homes, factories and office buildings.

In 2022, with the rate of inflation threatening to reach double-digit levels, as had been the case in 1979, Fed watchers naturally assumed that the Fed would again jack up interest rates high enough to cause a recession large enough to crush inflation. To their surprise, the Fed engineered a soft landing, bringing down the rate of inflation without causing a recession.

Read: Inflation is ‘far from dead’: Why one large asset manager doubts U.S. can hit 2%

Hanke’s reasoning was more dogmatic, focusing on the U.S. money supply rather than interest rates. He has long held that the quantity theory of money provides a tight linkage between money and inflation. So if, for example, helicopters were to fly around the country dropping money from the sky, thereby doubling the money supply, prices would also double, and life would proceed otherwise undisturbed.

There are several problems with this simplistic model. One is that it assumes that velocity — the ratio of gross domestic product to the money supply —is constant. If this ratio were 5, for example, then, on average, each dollar would be used five times a year to purchase domestically produced goods and services. There is no reason why this ratio should be 5 or any other particular number, especially since money is used to purchase many things that are not included in GDP, including intermediate goods, imports, stocks and other financial assets, along with real estate and other existing real assets.

A second problem is that there is no clearly best way to measure money. Along with many other monetarists, Hanke favors M2, a measurement that includes cash, a variety of bank deposits and retail money-market funds. The idea is that M2 measures readily available funds that people can spend if they want to. The elephant in the room is that many purchases are made with credit cards and consumer and business loans. There is no good way to measure the extent to which these constrain spending.

Nonetheless, Hanke has often relied on the quantity theory of money to argue that there is a tight one-for-one link between M2 and inflation. For example, in 2023 he wrote that “velocity and real output growth are very close to being constant, and … the money supply growth rate and inflation have a near one-to-one relationship.”

That conclusion is demonstrably wrong, but my concern here is with Hanke’s August 2022 prediction of a “whopper of a recession” in 2023 based on a slowing of M2 growth.

We Make The Markets Make Sense

Understand how today's global business practices, market dynamics, economic policies and more impact you with real-time news and analysis from MarketWatch.
Monetarists love to point accusatory fingers at the Fed.
 
Hanke is hardly the last monetarist standing. A Jan. 7 Motley Fool article noted that M2 has dropped by 2% over the past year and warned that “declines in M2 have historically been a harbinger of economic downturns.” Though the article did note that the historical episodes were more than a bit dated (1878, 1893, 1921 and 1931-1933), it nonetheless gave an ominous warning: “The previous four instances all resulted in deflationary depressions for the U.S. economy, along with a sizable increase in the unemployment rate.”

Monetarists love to point accusatory fingers at the Fed, but the U.S. central bank does not directly control monetary aggregates like M2. The Fed uses open-market operations to control the monetary base — currency outside banks plus bank reserves. M2 and other monetary aggregates are determined endogenously by public decisions about how to allocate their wealth among things that are or are not included in M2.

Another complicating factor is that the U.S. dollar is the official currency in several countries, is an unofficial medium of exchange in many others, and is widely held by central banks as foreign-exchange reserves. Almost half of all U.S. currency is now held outside of the United States.

The bottom line is that there is no persuasive reason why M2 should be tightly linked to the monetary base. In practice, it isn’t. This figure of the ratio of M2 to the monetary base shows how loose the connection is. The precipitous drop in the ratio of M2 to the monetary base in 2008 was due to the Fed pumping up the monetary base to keep the Great Recession from turning into the second Great Depression while M2 barely budged. It is deeply misleading to call M2 the money supply, as if this were controlled by the Fed.

 

These various considerations do not mean that the Fed is impotent. Central bankers can certainly shrivel liquidity and jack up interest rates in order to cause a recession whenever they feel it is in our best interests to be unemployed. What these considerations do mean is that it is foolish to think that there is a tight link between M2 and either inflation or output, and that it is hazardous to make predictions based on wiggles and jiggles in M2.

Gary N. Smith, Fletcher Jones professor of economics at Pomona College, is the author of dozens of research articles and 17 books including, most recently, “The Power of Modern Value Investing: Beyond Indexing, Algos, and Alpha,” co-authored with Margaret Smith (Palgrave Macmillan, 2023).

[ 打印 ]
閱讀 ()評論 (0)
評論
目前還沒有任何評論
登錄後才可評論.