Two years – 1982 and 2007 – frame the window of my experience as an economist at Morgan Stanley. When I walked in the door a quarter century ago, my focus was on a $3 trillion high-inflation
As I look back on the journey, I am struck by three macro milestones: At the top of my list is the extraordinary disinflation of the past 25 years. When I began working at Morgan Stanley, the ravages of
During the second half of the 1970s and the early 1980s, we agonized endlessly on how to arrest the Great Inflation. In retrospect, the cure was painfully simple – a wrenching monetary tightening. It took the vision and courage of Paul Volcker to pull it off – at one point in 1981 pushing the federal funds rate up to 19%. Ironically, central banks may be better equipped to fight high inflation than they are to preserve the gains of low inflation. While the new religion of monetary discipline succeeded in keeping inflation and inflationary expectations in check, the confluence of two powerful structural forces – the IT revolution and globalization – took a secular disinflation to the brink of an unwelcome deflation.
The
Globalization is certainly on a par with the other two milestones of the past 25 years. In this case, the comparison between 1982 and 2007 is like day and night. I walked into this job when global trade stood at just 18% of world GDP; this year, that ratio is likely to hit a record 32%. The problem with globalization is that we have done a lousy job in understanding and explaining it. And by “we” I mean my fellow economists, policy makers, politicians, business leaders, and other pundits. Far from the nirvana promised by the imagery of a “flat world” and the ecstasy of the “win-win” mantra, the road to globalization has led to saving and current-account imbalances, income disparities, and trade tensions – all having the potential to spark a very destabilizing backlash. The threat of just such a backlash remains a clear risk in today’s environment.
Notwithstanding those concerns, globalization has been a huge success – at least on one level. Despite persistent and devastating poverty in many poor countries, there has been a doubling of per capita GDP growth in the developing world over the past decade. What is still missing in this newfound prosperity is a key element of sustainability – the emergence of consumer-driven growth models in these still largely export- and investment-led economies. At the same time, in the rich countries of the developed world, the benefits of globalization have accrued far more to the owners of capital than to the providers of labor; labor shares of national income in the major developed economies are at record lows, whereas the shares going to capital are at record highs. Moreover, the distribution of gains within the labor share of the developed economies has become increasingly skewed toward the very few at the upper end of the income distribution – at the expense of those in the middle and at the lower end. Therein lie the seeds for a potentially powerful backlash: As the pendulum of economic power has swung from labor to capital, the pendulum of political power is now in the process of swinging back from a pro-capital stance to that which provides support for labor. The case for trade protectionism – especially in the
In one sense, these past 25 years have been an era of powerful transitions – transitions from high to low inflation, from stagnant to rapid productivity growth, and from closed to open economies. Transitions, by definition, have a finite duration. A key challenge for the global economy and world financial markets is what happens after these transitions have run their course – when disinflation comes to an end, when the productivity revival has crested, and when globalization hits its structural limits in terms of import penetration in the developed world and investment-led growth in the developing world. Don’t get me wrong – a post-transition climate need not be characterized as a return to rapid inflation, stagnant productivity growth, or trade protectionism. The endgame could be considerably more benign – modest inflation, “adequate” productivity growth, and a leveling out of the global trade share of world GDP. While these outcomes offer less dynamism to the global economy than we have seen in recent years, they do not represent relapses to more problematic macro climates. At the same time, such post-transition scenarios may well deny world financial markets the high-octane fuel that has produced such spectacular results over the past 25 years.
The jury is obviously out on these important questions – as well as on the inevitable transitions to come. My favorite candidates in that regard: productivity catch-ups in the developed world, consumer-led growth in the developing world, a world coming to grips with climate change, and financial solutions to the demographics of aging. There can be no mistaking the world’s increasingly robust coping mechanisms in dealing with recent and prospective challenges. In fact, as I look back on the past quarter century, what astonishes me the most is speed – how quickly the world has come to grips with structural issues like productivity and globalization and how equally quickly the Great Inflation was brought to an end. All this underscores the one lesson from economic history that rings truer than ever – the axiom of an ever-accelerating pace of change. Just like
The world today is obviously a very different place than it was 25 years ago. But let me assure you that back in 1982 there was no inkling of what was to come. I have been privileged to bear witness to an utterly astonishing period in the transformation of the global economy. I have relished the financial-market debate that has arisen out of this transformation. I wouldn’t trade that experience for anything. And now it’s off to
Summary and conclusions
We are refreshing our currency forecasts. While keeping our view on EUR/USD and USD/JPY essentially unchanged (EUR/USD to trade below 1.30 and USD/JPY to eventually break lower in 2008, conditional on several assumptions), we are revising up our forecasts for the commodity currencies (AUD, NZD and CAD). We believe that the global economy will continue to benefit from trade and financial globalisation. While there may be sporadic inflation scares, we foresee an essentially ‘Goldilocks-like’ global environment. As a result, we expect risk-taking to resume after the bond markets stabilise, and continue to believe that emerging markets (EM) should, in general, be well placed to outperform.
Our last forecast update was on March 22, 2007. Back then, we called for another bout of generalised USD weakness in 2Q, as the
The main changes to our forecasts are limited to the commodity currencies: the CAD, AUD and NZD. I make the following points:
As the global economy accelerates, it is likely that inflationary pressures will also mount. But I believe that central banks will manage to stay ahead of the curve.
The strength (beyond 5.00% on the
The reason why we still have a downward trajectory for USD/JPY over the medium term is to reflect our view that, first, the Japanese economy is doing just fine (1Q GDP growth of 3.3% ranks it number two among the G10 economies, after Canada). If the global economy is indeed re-accelerating, then the chances of
Bottom line
We believe that the dollar should reassert itself as the
We believe that the core cause of currency misalignments may be financial globalisation. Specifically, the extraordinarily rapid pace of financial globalisation, which, in turn, was fueled by buoyant financial markets and low implied volatility, may have pushed most G10 exchange rates far away from the fair values (FVs) implied by traditional valuation models that are centred on real economic fundamentals.
This idea we have has several policy implications. First, exchange rates are likely to remain misaligned as long as financial markets remain buoyant. Only if we experience a violent bout of risk-reduction would the G10 exchange rates move back to their FVs. Second, a ‘Plaza-like’ intervention effort to wrestle the exchange rates back toward their FVs may not be successful, since central banks would need to counter the structural forces, rather than fickle speculative flows, of global capital. This means that the shift in focus in
Exchange rate fair valuation
We have updated our quarterly FV calculations; there were no major changes to these estimates from the previous set. Specifically, EUR/USD, GBP/USD and USD/JPY remain grossly overvalued. EUR/JPY is still the most misaligned cross in the G10 space. The three commodity currencies, the AUD, NZD and CAD, also remain meaningfully mis-priced. Like the JPY, the CHF is also undervalued.
Currency misalignments are here to stay?
The G10 exchange rates have been misaligned for so long that we are starting to wonder if we are missing a part of the story, i.e., there may be important qualifications we need to acknowledge when interpreting the traditional approach to currency valuation.
We have the following thoughts:
· Thought 1. Financial versus trade globalisation. Most valuation frameworks, including ours, are centred on different aspects of the real economy. For example, productivity growth, the terms of trade and fiscal positions are all concepts that are more closely related to the real economy than to the financial markets. While equity and bond prices should indirectly reflect these fundamental features of an economy in question, large cross-border capital flows, which could be driven by factors other than the real fundamentals, could have substantive effects on exchange rates.
Two good examples are the JPY and CHF. It is remarkable that the currencies of two of the largest net savers in the world are also the weakest in the world, despite the fact that Japan’s 1Q growth was 3.3% — faster than any of the G7 countries except for Canada — and Switzerland’s 1Q growth was 3.2%. Further, both of these economies are growing above potential.
EUR/JPY is another example. Most valuation models suggest that this cross rate is extremely overvalued. However, the trend from 2001 has been powerful and definitive. Our ‘Global Funnelling Hypothesis’ is a capital flows framework, divorced from the relative economic fundamentals of
The fundamental variables that used to dictate currency trends — and are key input variables to our valuation framework — for the time being no longer seem to have the same impact on exchange rates that they used to. Instead, capital flows and nominal variables (such as cash interest rates) seem to dominate. Importantly, during the sharp risk-reduction in February/March, all of the G10 exchange rates we track moved toward their fair values! This suggests to us that capital flows, not economic fundamentals, somehow dominate the currency markets, and have played a critical role in pushing exchange rates into territories that are considered ‘misaligned’ relative to the real economies.
· Thought 2. The US Senate Finance Committee’s proposed bill is not bad. In the bill put forward on Wednesday by Senators Baucus, Grassley, Schumer and Graham, it was proposed that, if currency misalignments resulting from distorted policies (the ‘malign’ type of currency misalignments) are not resolved after 360 days, the US Treasury, in consultation with the Fed, could consider outright currency intervention. We have these thoughts:
First, this bill is not nearly as protectionist as it could have been, as it does not contain automatic triggers for countervailing duties.
Second, it does not mandate but only allows the Treasury to decide on outright currency intervention. Assuming that the US Treasury tries to do things in the best economic, not political, interest of the
Third, one way we judge to see if a policy is ‘good’ is to ask what the economic impact would be if other countries were to adopt the same policy. We believe that this particular bill is sensible enough that if Euroland and
Fourth, in practice, however, there would be operational issues, particularly regarding emerging market currencies such as the CNY. If the US Treasury were to decide to intervene to sell dollars and buy CNY, it would be difficult for it to implement this trade without the consent of
Fifth, this bill presumes that the JPY misalignment is considered ‘benign’, while the CNY misalignment is considered ‘malign’. Under this bill, no action can be taken regarding the JPY.
· Thought 3. Measures of misalignments are subjective. Currency misalignments are essentially the differences between the spot exchange rates and what one may consider is the ‘correct’ price for the currency, based on some economic fundamental variables or other considerations. While this may sound straightforward in theory, in practice, there is no one ‘correct’ equilibrium price because different practitioners consider different variables in coming to that view. For example, for USD/CNY, there are estimates of misalignments ranging from 5% to 50%. In fact, in a recent paper issued by the US Treasury, the subjective nature of currency valuation was highlighted as a source of major policy complication.
The subjective nature of currency valuation will make it difficult for the
· Thought 4. Currency interventions in the G10 space may not be effective. On Monday, June 11, 2007, the RBNZ conducted its first intervention since the float of the NZD in 1985. We are not convinced that its intervention will be effective in capping NZD/USD, though it could be an effective way for the RBNZ to accumulate some foreign reserves. Like many other countries, the RBNZ faces the ‘impossible trinity’ or the policy ‘trilemma’ of trying to target both interest rates and the exchange rate with an open capital account. If we are right that global capital flows have fundamentally distorted exchange rates and pushed them away from their FVs, the RBNZ would be ‘taking on’ these private sector flows. In the end, 8.00% of ‘risk-free’ government bond will likely remain attractive to many investors in the world.
Bottom line
We have become introspective about the concept of fair valuation of exchange rates, and have come to the view that FV calculations may be fundamentally ‘biased’ in that they are usually based on real economic fundamentals. But with financial globalisation and the sharp surge in cross-border asset holdings, persistent exchange rate misalignments could simply reflect differences between capital markets and the real economies. This hypothesis of ours suggests that exchange rates will likely stay mis-aligned, as long as financial globalisation continues, and that policy makers should exercise care when contemplating intervening in the currency markets.